» Articles » PMID: 23341593

Evolution of Fairness in the One-shot Anonymous Ultimatum Game

Overview
Specialty Science
Date 2013 Jan 24
PMID 23341593
Citations 56
Authors
Affiliations
Soon will be listed here.
Abstract

Classical economic models assume that people are fully rational and selfish, while experiments often point to different conclusions. A canonical example is the Ultimatum Game: one player proposes a division of a sum of money between herself and a second player, who either accepts or rejects. Based on rational self-interest, responders should accept any nonzero offer and proposers should offer the smallest possible amount. Traditional, deterministic models of evolutionary game theory agree: in the one-shot anonymous Ultimatum Game, natural selection favors low offers and demands. Experiments instead show a preference for fairness: often responders reject low offers and proposers make higher offers than needed to avoid rejection. Here we show that using stochastic evolutionary game theory, where agents make mistakes when judging the payoffs and strategies of others, natural selection favors fairness. Across a range of parameters, the average strategy matches the observed behavior: proposers offer between 30% and 50%, and responders demand between 25% and 40%. Rejecting low offers increases relative payoff in pairwise competition between two strategies and is favored when selection is sufficiently weak. Offering more than you demand increases payoff when many strategies are present simultaneously and is favored when mutation is sufficiently high. We also perform a behavioral experiment and find empirical support for these theoretical findings: uncertainty about the success of others is associated with higher demands and offers; and inconsistency in the behavior of others is associated with higher offers but not predictive of demands. In an uncertain world, fairness finishes first.

Citing Articles

Dynamics of cooperation in concurrent games.

Rossetti C, Hauser O, Hilbe C Nat Commun. 2025; 16(1):1524.

PMID: 39934104 PMC: 11814277. DOI: 10.1038/s41467-025-56083-7.


Evolutionary mechanisms that promote cooperation may not promote social welfare.

Han T, Duong M, Perc M J R Soc Interface. 2024; 21(220):20240547.

PMID: 39592014 PMC: 11597467. DOI: 10.1098/rsif.2024.0547.


Emergence of cooperation in the one-shot Prisoner's dilemma through Discriminatory and Samaritan AIs.

Zimmaro F, Miranda M, Fernandez J, Moreno Lopez J, Reddel M, Widler V J R Soc Interface. 2024; 21(218):20240212.

PMID: 39317332 PMC: 11639149. DOI: 10.1098/rsif.2024.0212.


Deliberately ignoring inequality to avoid rejecting unfair offers.

Offer K, Mischkowski D, Rahwan Z, Engel C Commun Psychol. 2024; 2(1):48.

PMID: 39242970 PMC: 11332100. DOI: 10.1038/s44271-024-00093-6.


Are Deaf College Students More Sensitive to Unfair Information? Evidence from an ERP Study.

Sun L, Dong Q, Du X, Wei D Brain Sci. 2024; 14(8).

PMID: 39199481 PMC: 11352934. DOI: 10.3390/brainsci14080788.


References
1.
Rand D, Arbesman S, Christakis N . Dynamic social networks promote cooperation in experiments with humans. Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A. 2011; 108(48):19193-8. PMC: 3228461. DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1108243108. View

2.
Manapat M, Rand D, Pawlowitsch C, Nowak M . Stochastic evolutionary dynamics resolve the Traveler's Dilemma. J Theor Biol. 2012; 303:119-27. PMC: 3348410. DOI: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2012.03.014. View

3.
Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Camerer C, Fehr E, Gintis H . "Economic man" in cross-cultural perspective: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behav Brain Sci. 2005; 28(6):795-815. DOI: 10.1017/S0140525X05000142. View

4.
Amir O, Rand D, Gal Y . Economic games on the internet: the effect of $1 stakes. PLoS One. 2012; 7(2):e31461. PMC: 3283743. DOI: 10.1371/journal.pone.0031461. View

5.
Ohtsuki H, Iwasa Y . The leading eight: social norms that can maintain cooperation by indirect reciprocity. J Theor Biol. 2005; 239(4):435-44. DOI: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2005.08.008. View